Monday, December 24, 2012

Hindu Growth Rate as Global Growth Rate



Introduction
Competitive drive in economic evolutionary history is perhaps the oldest and most continuous characteristic of social structures, fundamental economic institutions and mechanisms in the process of achieving economic prosperity. Systems that are more open to the outside world have done better and are postulated to do better relative to less competitive societies (Smith 1776). It is argued in this paper that Vedic, Sanatan Dharma or Hindu (hereafter used interchangeably) culture has expounded and exhibited this critical characteristic of openness in thought and practice over several millennia.  (Sri Aurobindo 1959). Further, Hindu society has sustained itself at a steady rate and is expected to continue to do so despite suffering deprecating comments on its so-called low rate of growth by its own economists who have made the Hindu Rate of Growth synonymous with low rate of growth and low rate with Hinduism (Ahluwalia 2005). In this chapter we discuss key drivers in the Hindu system to support the hypothesis and view that the Hindu Rate of Growth is sustainable as the long-term global rate of growth.

The Hindu Rate of Growth as the Sustainable Growth Rate for the World Economy
 Hindu value system is, perhaps the oldest, certainly among the oldest value systems in the settled societies and economies (Kesavan 1997, Srinivasan 1997) in the world. The Hindu Rate of Growth corresponds to a low rate up to 3 percent experienced by India’s post-independence economy roughly from 1950 to 1980, as made famous by the Indian economist Raj Krishna, albeit with a condescending view. It is also a good proxy for the long-term rate of growth of the Indian economy over several thousand years.  Thus the low rate of growth was a reality before and after the British Raj in India.  The low rate continued in the post-colonial period from 1947 to 1997. In the short-term, the rate has doubled exceeding six percent in recent years.
The Turkish, Persian, Afghan, and Mogul invasions and their subsequent rule over parts of India from the tenth to the eighteenth century had considerable economic, social and cultural interaction and assimilation in the local people and in Vedic India. Eighteenth century had a considerable adverse economic and an anti–Vedic impact on the native population along with a forced assimilation of some of the elements of diametrically opposite cultures.
Trading between India and the Near East as well as Europe goes back to antiquity. The British had gone to India as East India Trading Company chartered for the purpose of trading with India by Queen Elizabeth I in 1600. Their success allowed Britain under the then Prime Minister Disraeli to take governance of India from the Company.  Queen Victoria became the Empress of India in 1858. The British brought considerable Western influence for some 350 years on modern India. Other Europeans from Alexander the Great to the French, Portuguese, and Germans have also invaded, traded with, and impacted India over the millennia.
India had the highest income among all countries up to about 1500 CE when China emerged as the richest country followed by European powers, followed by the United States (Maddison 2003).  China is again among the largest economies in the world along with the US and EU and to be perhaps number one in terms of GDP in a few years.  In terms of per capita income, however, China is still only one-fifth of the US average. India is around one-tenth of the US real per capita income in 2011.
The Hindu Rate of Growth (HRG) is a controversial and derogatory expression used to refer to the low annual growth rate of the socialist economy of India before 1991, which was around 3.5 percent from 1950s to 1980s, while per capita income growth averaged 1.3% (Chart 3).The average US nominal GDP growth rate at that time was 6.2 percent while the real GDP growth rate, at 2005 prices, was 3.4 percent a year from 1930 to 2010 (Chart 1). India’s growth rate for the most recent thirty year short-term period from 1980 to 2010 by comparison is 6.11 percent a year (Chart 2).  Perhaps it is not a coincidence that the US rate of growth over the first two and a quarter centuries since 1776 is essentially the same. It is a remarkable similarity of growth rates.
Given the physical, and human resources and environmental constraints, it is most likely that the world economy will regress back to the sustainable HRG of about 3 to 4 percent a year.  The potential productivity gains from technology, better human capital and more financial capital  may make a more than 2 percent plus annual per capita real growth possible after allowing for a 1 to 1.5 percent growth of population.
We are not advocating low rates for India, the US or the world. Rather, our focus is on reality and not empty dreams, not to mention destructive parts of high growth rates on the environment, quality of life and indeed the sustainability of life on earth because of CO2 and other threats to the planet.   India is not going to have China's high growth rates for any significant period. Even China is projected to have less than 6 percent a year in the next 30 years versus the 10 percent in the last 30 years. The Hindu Rate and Irving Fisher’s 3 to 4 percent real sustainable long term rate is most likely to prevail over the long haul.  The Hindu Rate is not bad notwithstanding the desire to grow faster and achieve higher living standards similar to the West sooner.  The Hindu Rate has made America what it is with growth at 3 to 4 percent a year for a very long period of 300 to 500 years since perhaps Columbus, certainly since 1776 as far as recorded numbers show, of course with very different market basket and technologies overtime. 
India has also experienced low growth rate for a long time. India’s per capita income was Rs. 168 in 1857 and Rs. 187 in 1900. Thus, there was hardly any change over a period of more than 40 years while the British government directly ruled India. The per capita income fluctuated between Rs. 168 to Rs. 205 but it had a mere 10 percent or 0.25 percent growth a year over a 43 year period (Chart 3).
As can be seen in table 1, growth rates in the world and the developed countries also converge towards the Hindu Rate of Growth in the long run.  It is quite understandable that impatient economists and others would like to have developing countries grow at a faster rate to catch up to the income levels of developed countries that  they would find India’s post-independence rate of growth to be inadequate. The cultural connection is not inappropriate, but   judgments such as like Raj Krishna’s were hastily made. He and his contemporaries confused income levels and the desirability of achieving those levels with rates of growth.  Here and now of Ram Das  (Dass 1971) and Paul Sartre  (Sartre 1943) gripped them as they Westernized themselves in Boston, London, Paris, Chicago, New York and Washington, D.C.   Had the impatient Westernized Indian scholars conducted analysis of long term growth rates in the United States and other developed countries, they would have been more modest in their criticism of Hinduism and India.
            There are sound reasons for the long-term similar low rates of growth in India, the United States and Europe. Every American textbook makes reference to the 3 percent real rate of return (or GDP growth rate) that is based on a study of returns on investment in American industry from 1870 to 1900 by Irving Fisher (Fisher 1930). He found the 3 percent real return in his empirical studies published early 1900s.  His work and analysis had made an implicit forecast which has generally held up from 1900 to 2011 with regard to the annual growth rate of American GDP at about 3.  GDP can be interpreted as the return on the total capital stock, as the marginal efficiency of capital or the internal rate of return, of the United States (Fisher 1930). The stability of this low number at 3 percent, in the context of remarkable innovations increasing productivity of labor and capital over the last one hundred years and more, can also be termed the HRG as there are many similarities in business and cultural context in India and the United States.
Chart 2: India Growth Rate
Chart1: US Growth Rate

                           
Chart 3: Per capita Income in India from 1857 to 1900.  
Table 1: GDP Growth Rates in the World Economy

  1996
 1997
 1998
 1999
 2000
 2001
 2002
 2003
 2004
 2005
 2006
 2007
 2008
 2009
 2010  


World
 3.7
 3.9
 2.2
 3.9
 4.8
 2.2
 2.6
 3.4
 4.8
 4.5
 5.0
 4.9
 2.4
 -1.1
 3.9

Advanced Economies
 2.9
 3.4
 2.3
 4.2
 4.2
 1.5
 1.7
 1.9
 3 .1
 2.7
 3.0
 2 .7
 0.2
 -3.5
 3.0

      Emerging and Developing          Countries
 5.1
 4.9
 2.0
 3.5
 5.8
 3.6
 4.2
 6.1
 7.5
 7.4
 8.1
 8.5
 6.1
 3.2
    ...

Developing Asia
 8.4
 6.1
 2.7
 6.2
 6.6
 5.9
 6.6
 8.6
 8.5
 9.6
 10.3
 11.1
 7.7
 7.2
 ...

        Europe
 0.8
 3.0
 -1.0
 2.6
 7.6
 2.4
 4.7
 6.5
 7.4
 6.3
 7.3
 6.8
 4.2
  ...
 ...
                                                        Middle East and north Africa
 5.2
 3.7
 4.0
 1.8
 4.9
 3.1
 4.0
 6.7
 6.0
 5.5
 5.8
 6.1
 6.2
 ...
 ... 

Sub-Saharan Africa
 5.1
 3.6
 2.8
 4.0
 3.9
 4 .4
 4.1
 3.7
 6.1
 6.4
 5.7
 6.0
 4.6
 -0.1
 ...

Western Hemisphere
 3.4
 5.2
 2.2
 0.4
 4.1
  0.6
 0.1
 2.0
 6.1
 4.6
 5.6
 5.7
 4.2
 -2.0
 ...

Source: IMF Data: Chart 4: USA GDP Growth Rate


http://elibrarydata.imf.org/DataReport.aspx?c=1449326&d=33061&e=169393
Chart 4: US GDP Growth Rate
http://tradingeconomics.com/Economics/GDP-Growth.aspx?Symbol=USD
Year
GDP - real growth rate (%)
2000
5.5
2001
6
2002
4.3
2003
4.3
2004
8.3
2005
6.2
2006
8.4
2007
9.2
2008
9
2009
7.4

Chart 5: India GDP Growth Rate
http://www.indexmundi.com/g/g.aspx?c=in&v=66
GDP growth on an annual basis adjusted for inflation and expressed as percent.
Year
Gross domestic product, constant prices- India
1980
3.626
1981
6.176
1982
4.072
1983
6.365
1984
4.647
1985
4.891
1986
4.88
1987
4.153
1988
8.258
1989
6.81
1990
5.63
1991
2.136
1992
4.385
1993
4.939
1994
6.199
1995
7.351
1996
7.56
1997
10.328
1998
5.288
1999
3.273
2000
4.44
2001
3.885
2002
4.558
2003
6.852
2004
8.106
2005
9.167
2006
9.658
2007
9.886
2008
6.396
2009
5.678
2010
9.668
http://www.indexmundi.com/india/gdp_real_growth_rate.html





http://www.indexmundi.com/india/gdp_real_growth_rate.html




Chart 6: India-China GDP (per capita) 1950-2003
GDP development trends of China and India. GDP per capita (in 1990 dollars), Geary-Khamis data range 1950-2003.



The world as a whole and the advanced economies group reinforce the long-term growth rates in the United States and India as well from 1996 to 2010, as reported by the International Monetary Fund. The emerging markets and developing markets (including Brazil, Russia, India, and China) have higher rates in the same period. It remains to be seen whether 6 to 10 percent rates can be sustained over 30 to 50 years and longer. We are more hopeful of a 6 percent growth, and doubt a 10 percent growth.
 

References
Philippe Aghion and Rachel Griffith, Competition and Growth:  Reconciling Theory and Evidence. Cambridge: The MIT Press, 2005.
Montek Singh Ahluwalia, First Raj Krishna Memorial Lecture, Economic  Reforms for the Nineties. Jaipur, India: Department of Economics, University of Rajasthan, 2005.
Sri Aurobindo, The Foundations of Indian Culture. Pondicherry: Sri Aurobindo Ashram, 1959.
___________, The Secret of the Veda. Pondicherry: Sri Aurobindo Ashram, 1956.
___________, Essays on the Gita. Pondicherry: Sri Aurobindo Ashram, 9th Edition, 1996.
Ram Dass, Be Here Now. Hanuman Foundation, 1971.
________, The Only Dance There Is. New York: Anchor Books, 1974.
Edward F. Denison, Accounting for Slower Economic Growth: The United States in the 1970s.     Washington, D.C.: The Brookings Institution, 1979.
________________, Why Growth Rates Differ. Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution, 1967.
David Dollar and Aart Kraay, “Trade, Growth, and Poverty,” Finance and Development, September 2001.
Raymond Drake, Gods and Spacemen in the Ancient East. New York: Signet, 1968.
Daniel W. Drezner, “The Outsourcing Bogeyman.”  Foreign Affairs. May/June 2004.
Irving Fisher, Theory of Interest. 1930.
Benjamin M. Friedman, The Moral Consequences of Economic Growth. New York: Alfred A.   Knopf, 2005.
R.L. Kashyap and S. Sadgopan (eds.), Rigveda Samhita. Bangalore: Sri Aurobindo Kapali Sastry Institute of Vedic Culture, 1998.
Surendra K. Kaushik, "India’s Evolving Economic Model: A Perspective on Economic and          Financial Reforms", American Journal of Economics and Sociology, 56, 1, January 1997,      69-84.
Surendra K. Kaushik, - "India’s Democratic Economic Transformation", Challenge, Sept./Oct.     1996, 54-61.
Surendra K. Kaushik, "Economic and Political Integration of India in the World Community",     Indian American Community Welcomes Atalji, Souvenir, New York City, September 14,      2002.
Surendra K. Kaushik, Shorav Kaushik and Shobha Kaushik, “How higher education, in rural India helps human rights and entrepreneurship.” Journal of Asian Economics, 17, 2006, 29-34.
Surendra K.  Kaushik and Massimo Santicchia, “Global Financial Markets and India’s Opportunities." Business Journal, 15, 1, 1999.
Surendra K.  Kaushik and Massimo Santicchia, Global Financial Integration & Its Implications     for India. Delhi: Society for Economic and Social Research (SESR), 1999, Working Paper No. 1, 1-44.
Surendra K. Kaushik and Leonard Silk, “India’s Evolving Economic Model.”  Economic Policy,  Fall (1994) 17-24.
H.K. Kesavan, “The Vedas and Vedic Philosophy”, in Ananya: A Portrait of India, edited by S.N. Sridhar and Nirmal K. Mattoo, 137-156. New York: The Association of Indians in America, 1997.
Anjana Dharnidharka and Chandra Prakash Khetan  (eds.), The Future of India. Jhunjhunu: Sri Aurobindo Divine Life Trust,
Angus Maddison, The World Economy: Historical Statistics. Paris: OECD, 2003
Juan Mascaro, The Upanishads. Baltimore: Penguin Classics, 1965.
Jawahar Mulraj (ed.), Kautilya’s Arthashastra. Pune: Ameya Prakashan, Hinduja Foundation,       and Indian Merchants’ Chamber, 2005
Mangesh Nadkarni, India's Spiritual Destiny.  Sri Aurobindo Society, Pondicherry (in association with UBS Publishers' Distributors Pvt. Ltd, New Delhi).
Douglas C. North, Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance. Cambridge    University Press, 1990.
Jose Pereira, “The Significance of the Indic Religions for the West”, in Ananya: A Portrait of        India,  edited by S.N. Sridhar and Nirmal K. Mattoo, 125-136. New York: The         Association of Indians in America, 1997.
M.G. Prasad, Multi-faceted Vedic Hinduism.  New York: The Foundation for Arts and Sciences from    India (ARSI), 2010 (third edition).
______________, “Four objectives of life for individual and societal growth as per Hinduism”,
paper  presented  at  Fordham University conference on Hindu Economics,  June 2011.
S.R. Rao, “From the Indus Civilization to the Golden Age”, in Ananya: A Portrait of India,          edited by S.N. Sridhar and Nirmal K. Mattoo,35-62.  New York: The Association of         Indians in America, 1997.
William I.  Robinson, “Social Theory and Globalization: The Rise of a Transitional State.” In        Theory and Society 30: 157-200. 2001.
Jean-Paul Sartre, Being and Nothingness An Essay on Phenomenological Ontology (French: L'Être et le néant: Essai d'ontologie phénoménologique, 1943).
Ramakrishna Sharma, “tat tvam asi”.  E-mail comment: rsharma@gmail.com
Adam Smith, An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations. London: W.            Strahan and T. Cadell, First Edition, 1776.
S.N. Sridhar and Nirmal K. Mattoo (eds.), Ananya: A Portrait of India. Center for India Studies,  SUNY Stony Brook University and Association of Indian in America: New York.           2002.
T.N. Srinivasan, “Indian Economy Over Five Millennia: 3000 BCE to 2000CE”, in Ananya: A      Portrait of India, edited by S.N. Sridhar and Nirmal K. Mattoo, 435-473. New York: The     Association of Indians in America, 1997.
Prakash Tandon, ”Indian Trade and Finance: Historical Perspective”, in Ananya: A Portrait of      India, edited by S.N. Sridhar and Nirmal K. Mattoo, 473-490. New York: The         Association of Indians in America, 1997.
Sri Aurobindo Ashram Trust, A Divine Life Manifesto. Jhunjhunu, Rajasthan: Sri Aurobindo Divine Life Education Centre, 2nd. Edition, 1998.
Sri Aurobindo Ashram Trust, Complete Works of Sri Aurobindo. Pondicherry.
Sri Aurobindo Ashram Trust, The Light of Lights: Words of Sri Aurobindo (1), Diary 2011.
            Jhunjhunu: Sri Aurobindo Divine Life Trust, 2011.
Hrishikesh D. Vinod and Surendra K. Kaushik, “Human Capital and Economic Growth:   Evidence from Developing Countries.” The American Economist, Volume L1, No. 1,         Spring 2007.

No comments:

Post a Comment